Sunday, November 16, 2014

Factoid: Frozen is Japan's3rd Highest Grossing Movie

I stumbled over some news articles (here and here) from last June-July about the popularity of the movie "Frozen" in Japan. The film grossed close to a quarter billion dollars and is the third highest grossing film in Japan.

What I found particularly interesting was the list of the top ten highest grossing films that The Atlantic posted:


Looking at this list, several things struck me:
  1. 5 out of 10 movies are foreign to Japan (Titanic, Frozen, the first two Harry Potters, and Avatar
  2. 5 are animated (Spirited Away, Frozen Howl's Moving Castle, Princess Mononoke, and Ponyo)
  3. 7 are fantasies featuring children (all except Titanic, Bayside Shakedown, and Avatar)
  4. Only Bayside Shakedown (probably a terrible translation of its title) is a live action Japanese film (FYI-it is a police thriller involving murder, conspiracy and corruption)
  5. Only Titanic and Bayside Shakedown lack either a fantasy or scifi element.
The first point above goes to the effect of globalization on the movie industry. Japan has the 3rd largest GDP in the world, but half their top grossing films are foreign.

The other points more less speak to cultural proclivities. The Japanese seem to favor animation, stories about children, and stories with mystical elements. Though deeper analysis should be left to sociologists, I will speculate that animation and child characters both give an indirect expression of the world. 


Sunday, November 02, 2014

Venezuela Doubles Down on its Econ Fail

Venezuela is in a hole and its president seems determined to keep digging. AP reports that President Maduro is deploying teams of inspectors to enforce the governments price controls to a guarantee "a happy Christmas for the people."

Of course, anyone who has taken Econ101 should be able to predict that all this will do is guarantee more shortages and black market activity. The laws of supply and demand tell us that if you lower prices below the market equilibrium, than consumers will demand more and producers will produce less, creating a shortage. (I discussed this at some length in a post back in May and another back in February).

The government sees it differently. The shortages are blamed on black market vendors who buy goods at the government mandated price and then resell them at a higher price on the black market. It also claims that "bourgeoisie criminals" are waging an economic war on the government's policies. Among these criminals are smugglers who are bringing goods into the country to sell on the black market.

From the point of view of economic theory, this can only be described as nonsense. The black market only exists because of the price controls. Black marketeers can only make a profit because the government has set prices far too low (indeed the lower the government sets the prices the greater the shortage and larger the profit margin for black market sales). Furthermore, if the shortages were simply the result of hoarding and reselling the goods being produced, there would be plenty of domestic goods to meet demand and their would be no need for (or profit in) smuggling.

The thing is that the laws of supply and demand are not abstract concepts. The head of the Caracas Chamber of Commerce demonstrates this in the quote that closes out the article:
"There is a huge crisis of confidence in Venezuela," he said. The commercial sector "doesn't trust the government's economic policies or its ability to resolve problems. Experience tells us that with measures like these, you're left with empty shelves, little to no supplies, and closed businesses."
This is undoubtedly what will happen and is unlikely to produce a happy Christmas for anyone except those employed to enforce the laws.

What I find so infuriating about Venezuela's policy is that it flies in the face of China's experience. China has generally made policy reforms that allow businesses to make a profit when producing and allowing the market to set prices. What they have been slow to do is to fully privatize property ownership. Therefore, the Chinese brand of socialism has embraced market distribution of goods and services while going slow on privatizing capital. In Venezuela, they have left most capital outside of the oil sector in private hands but have focused on intervening in (read distorting)  the market system. In other words they have more fully embraced the parts of socialism that most socialists have come to reject.

Meanwhile, back at West Texas and Brent (as mentioned in a previous post), the price of oil has dropped precipitously and might continue to remain low into the second quarter of next year. This is going to slash Venezuela's already dwindling oil revenues. This suggests to me that things are about to get even worse for the country's economy and this should stoke political unrest.


Thursday, October 30, 2014

Ukraine's Elections Produce Solidly Pro-Western Parliament

Oxanna Shevel posted an analysis of the results from Ukraine's October 26 parliamentary election and the bottom line is that pro-western parties now hold a dominant majority and pro-Russian parties have been relegated to the sidelines. This is a shift from recent years when the parliament was more evenly divided between pro-European and pro-Russian parties, and the struggle between the two sides defined Ukrainian politics.

Now the parliament is largely split between the Popular Front (Prime Minister Arsenii Yatseniuk;s party) and the Petro Poroshenko’s Block (as the name proclaims, President Petro Poroshenko’sparty), each of which received about 22% of the vote. Other pro-European (or at least not pro-Russian) parties include Samopomich (11 percent of the vote), Radical Party of Oleh Liashko (7 percent), and Batkivshchyna (6 percent). The only pro-Russian party to clear the 5% threshold needed to gain seats in the parliament was the aptly named Opposition Block, which received 9 percent of the vote.

Since 50% of the seats in the Rada are directly elected, there are a number of independents that got elected and there is some sorting out to be done. However, it appears that the Opposition Block will have about 112 seats out of a total of 423, or 26% of the seats. This leaves 74% of the seats in the hands of pro-European parties and makes a number of different majority coalition arrangements possible.The significance of this is, as Shevel puts it,

With several possible configurations for the majority, a substantial number of deputies, and even entire parties, can drop out of a coalition without a coalition collapsing, or with a different but still pro-western coalition forming in its place. The pro-Russian Opposition Block is virtually relegated to be what it name says: an opposition.

Shevel argues that one of the key reasons for this electoral outcome is Putin's moves in eastern Ukraine. By annexing Crimea and supporting separatists in Donetsk and Luhansk, Putiin is partially responsible for cutting 4 million voters, a large majority of whom would have voted pro-Russian, from the Ukrainian political system. His actions have also affected attitudes among the rest of Ukraine's voters, shifting public opinion away from Russian and towards European.

Shevel concludes,

If Putin’s fear after the victory of the Euromaidan uprising and the fall of Yanukovych was that Ukraine would turn decisively westward and leave Russia’s orbit, then by his actions in Crimea and the Donbas, Putin, ironically, may have helped created the very reality he wanted to avoid: Ukraine’s pro-western orientation is stronger now that every before. Russia had many levers over Ukraine that did not disappear after the fall of Yanukovych – including gas, trade, and the pro-Russian voters in the south and east of Ukraine – and Putin could have chosen to utilize these levers to prevent Ukraine from moving westward.  Had Putin not annexed Crimea and sponsored separatist conflict in eastern Ukraine, Ukraine would certainly have had a very different parliament after these elections, with a much stronger representation by pro-Russian parties, through which Russia could have continued to exert leverage on political developments in Ukraine.  As it is, Russia’s allies in the Ukrainian parliament will now likely number just over a quarter of its composition.
So, is Putin an idiot? That depends on what you think he is after. If you posit that he is trying to divert Ukraine away from the west, he doesn't appear to be doing a good job of it. However, if you posit that he is pursuing domestic political and economic goals (such as solidifying support among Russian conservatives and extending state control of the economy), then you might reach a different conclusion (or at least you would have to take a different path to get to it). More on that later.

Wednesday, October 29, 2014

Oil Prices

I hardly need to post a link to inform anyone that gas prices are down. You are probably already aware that crude oil prices have dropped over the past month or so from around $100 to the mid 80s.

What might be news is that Goldman Sachs has forecast 2015 crude oil prices to be even lower. They are predicting prices to be around $75/barrel in the West Texas market and $85 in the Brent market in the first quarter of 2015. They also predict that prices will drop another $5 lower in both markets in the second quarter. Of course, as the Reuters reported lined to above mentions, other forecasters are more bullish about oil price, but we at least have some reason to contemplate the probability that oil prices will remain low for the next 6 months or so.

Beyond the relief this will provide consumers at the gas pump, a period of lower than usual oil prices will have a big impact on Russia. Even members of the Russian government are acknowledging that lower oil prices are a serious blow to their budget and economy.

This blow may be politically significant to the extent that the regime depends on the flow of oil revenue to pay off its supporters. Where Western sanctions have been inflicting pain on the Russian economy and consumers at large, a drop in oil prices diminishes the government's primary revenue stream. Thus, it may come closer to weakening Putin's hold on power than any of the sanctions yet employed.

Of course, unlike sanctions, oil prices won't go up if Russia complies with Western demands and prices are bound to rally at some point in 2015. Therefore, low oil prices might weaken Putin in general without providing more pressure to act in the desired way vis-a-vis Ukraine. Still, it is an interesting development that is worth watching.

It will also be interesting to see what impact lower oil prices have on Venezuela's teetering economy.

Sunday, October 19, 2014

Factoid: Gold Prices

So, Richard Petty is now hawking gold coins.Part of his spiel is that gold is a safe bet because it is a :hard asset."

The problem with this is that the price of gold is just that, a price. Therefore, like all prices, it is dependent on the values judgments of buyer  and sellers.

If you take a look at the history of real gold prices (see graph) you can see that when you adjust for inflation, gold has some serious ups and downs. Gold prices peaked in 1980 at about $1820 an ounce in 2012 dollars and did so again at about $1825 in 2001. (Note: from 1933 to 1975, it was illegal for private citizens in the US to own gold bullion without a special license, so the modern market for gold only dates back to the end of that period.)

It is important to note that after the peak in 1980, gold lost half its value in the next 3 years and then steadily declined (in inflation adjusted dollars) to a nadir of $338 an ounce (in 2012 dollars) in 2001. From 2001-2011 it rose at a significant rate, but has recently lost 1/3 from its value since the 2001 peak.

Not exactly a hard asset.



Wednesday, October 15, 2014

Hall of Shame: US pays off Brazil to keep Cotton Subsidies

Krzysztof J. Pelc has a post in the Monkey Cage about the deal between the US and Brazil in which the US pays Brazil $300 million to settle Brazil's complaint about US cotton subsidies which Brazil claims depresses the world price of cotton.

Such payoffs are explicitly against the WTO's rules but there is little  he WTO can do about it. As Pelc explains:
The key to understanding this outcome is to know that the WTO relies on a decentralized enforcement system. There is no WTO public prosecutor or WTO attorney general: No violation is challenged unless another member state files a formal complaint. And while this is meant to reassure states wary of ceding too much sovereignty to the institution, it also means that the system is ripe for collusion. In this case, the United States only had to satisfy Brazil to make the case go away — for a while.

Wednesday, September 10, 2014

Factoid: Current State of the US Economy

Mark Perry posted  the following graph of Real GDP and Employment before and after the Great Recession:


What it shows is that the economy is producing 7.65% more GDP than it was before the recession but is using 227,000 less people to do it. (Note: 227k people equates to 0.15% of the work forces so we can say that the economy is employing about the same number of people as before.)

As Perry puts it: "The fact that we’ve been able to greatly expand national output with fewer inputs (workers) represents a huge increase in economic efficiency, but has also left us with a lingering 'jobless recovery' and an economy that is struggling to create new, post-recession employment opportunities for millions of Americans."

Thursday, August 21, 2014

Factoid: Creative Destruction in the Fortune 500

Mark Perry had a post on his Carpe Diem blog the other day in which he compared the Fortune 500 list from 1955 with the list from 2014. He notes that 88% of the companies that were on the list in 1955 are not on the list in 2014 (conversely, only 12% of the companies have remained on the list after 59 years).

He also links to a Forbes article by Steve Denning that makes the point that the life expectancy of firms on the Fortune 500 list has been declining over the years. In the early 20th century, a firm tended to stay on the list for up to 75 years, today they only stay on for 15 years. Denning includes the following graph from Richard Foster's work on creative destruction to illustrate the point:


The point here is that declining longevity at the top of the heap is a sign of dynamism in the economy. As Perry puts it:

That’s a lot of churning and creative destruction, and it’s probably safe to say that almost all of today’s Fortune 500 companies will be replaced by new companies in new industries over the next 59 years, and for that we should be thankful. The constant turnover in the Fortune 500 is a positive sign of the dynamism and innovation that characterizes a vibrant consumer-oriented market economy, and that dynamic turnover is speeding up in today’s hyper-competitive global economy.

Saturday, August 16, 2014

Factoids: Matt Ridley's Reasons to be Cheerful

Economics is often referred to as the dismal science, supposed in reference to Malthus' predictions of cycles of famine and death, but a lot of economists are positively upbeat about the condition of humanity. Perhaps this is because, by most  objective measures, the material well being of people has been improving for the last few centuries.

Matt Ridley, the Rational Optimist, tends to specialize in pointing out the good news and he has a post on his blog covering the reasons to be cheerful even if there is plenty of bad news in the world this summer. The post has some interesting charts showing the declining price of light, increasing GDP, and declining deaths due to severe weather.

Mark Perry did a good job of grouping and highlighting Ridleys' points, so rather than do so myself, I will refer you to Perry's post for a more digestable version of Ridley's reasons for cheer.

Tuesday, August 12, 2014

The Threat of Foreign Fighters Returning Home

There is considerable outrage in the press over the photo of a young boy holding a severed head in Syria. Part of what is fueling the story is the reports that the boy is the son of an Australian Jihadist who traveled to Syria to join the fight. Thus, the story feeds into concerns about so-called "foreign fighters."

Beyond concerns for the children in the immediate case, there are concerns that foreign fighters will return home to plot terror attacks. Indeed, US Secretary of State Kerry, who is currently in Australia, called for talks on how to handle foreign fighters.

However, research by Thomas Hegghammer suggests that these concerns may be overblown. In a Monkey Cage post from September 2013, Hegghammer summarizes the results of a paper he published in the APSR, Hegghammer collected data on foreign fighters and he summarized his findings as follows:
My article tries to answer these questions by looking at where Western jihadists have chosen to fight over the years and why. I rely on open-source data, including a new dataset on jihadi plots in the West from 1990-2010 and data on foreign fighter flows. My five main findings are:
  • Foreign fighting is by far the most common activity. Foreign fighters outnumber domestic attackers by at least 3 to 1 (over 900 vs. 300 individuals over 20 years).
  • Western jihadists seem to prefer foreign fighting for normative reasons. They heed religious authorities who consider fighting in warzones more legitimate than killing civilians in Western cities.
  • Most foreign fighters appear not to leave with the intention to train for a domestic operation.  However, a minority do acquire this motivation after their departure.
  • Most foreign fighters never return for domestic plots. In my data, at most 1 in 9 foreign fighters came home to roost.
  • Those foreign fighters who do return are significantly more effective operatives than non-veterans. They act as entrepreneurs and concoct plots that are twice as likely to kill.

Monday, August 11, 2014

Pape, Ruby and Bauer Criticize GTD Data on Suicide Terrorism

In a July 21 Monkey Cage post, Robert Pape, Kevin Ruby and Vincent Bauer criticize the Global Terrorism Database's (GTD) data that shows a recent increase in suicide terrorist attacks. As they see it:
The main trouble with the GTD is that its collection standards have changed several times, making it an inappropriate source for measuring trends. The GTD was initially funded by the DHS in 2006 and began by compiling data from three independent projects, each with its own collection methodology and standards for inclusion: one standard of collection from 1970 until 1998, another through 2008 and another through 2011. It was not until November 2011 that the GTD became responsible for collecting its own data, at which point it changed its methodology and standards. No surprise, the type and number of events in the data set changed every time the methodology changed.

The authors note that the Chicago Project on Security and Terrorism (CPOST), which has used a consistent methodology for tracking instances of suicide terrorism,  identified more instances in 2007 (the previous spike in event) than did the GTD and less in the recent couple of years (see graph here).


Thursday, August 07, 2014

Russian Sanctions of Western Food and Possible Intervention in Ukraine

Note: I am traveling this week and only have time for a short note.

A few days ago I noted that Putin was softening his rhetoric on the heat from the west, but now he has imposed bans on the import of food from western nations and appears poised to militarily intervene in Eastern Ukraine. If you recall, the point I was trying to make about Putin was that he has the domestic political freedom to turn on a dime and this makes him a bit unpredictable.

Also, if Russia uses the pretext of a humanitarian intervention in the face of an increasingly deadly Ukrainian offensive against seperatists, this subterfuge will probably be enough to forestall any really threatening response from NATO. Though in the long run Putin may be digging a deeper hole for Russia, it's probably a safe bet that a limited use of force will produce little reaction. And, if something unforeseen happens to make that bet go bad, Putin has the flexibility to pull back. When it comes to making modest opportunistic moves, it's good to be a leader of a small coalition regime and miserable to be in the position of trying to predict exactly what one will do.

Then there are the sanctions on food. While banning western agricultural imports will impose costs on European and US farmers, the bigger impact is likely to be on Russian food prices and, thus, on Russian consumers. However, from Putin's point of view, any problems caused by price increases and shortages will be balanced by the opportunity to intervene in local markets and exert more control on revenue flows.  After all, you can't get extort much out of a market for plentiful and inexpensive goods.

Things change when you have higher prices and a shortage of supply. Increased government intervention in the market will not only be tolerated but demanded. Though Putin isn't particularly sensitive to public opinion, it is always easier to implement a popular policy than an unpopular one. The increased control over the market will make it easier to reward friends and punish enemies, and increased prices will make those rewards and punishments larger. This will in turn enhance Putin's chances of political survival despite the pain inflicted on Russian consumers.


Wednesday, July 23, 2014

Selectorate Theory's take on Democratic Leaders vs Dictators at War

In discussing the effect of coalition size on the behavior of leaders in war, Bueno de Mesquta (BDM) and Smith contrast the advice of Sun Tzu with that of Casper Weinberger. BDM and Smith summarize Sun Tzu's advice for kings contemplating war as follows:
  1. Quick action is more important than outnumbering an adversary
  2. Mobilize only enough resources for a quick campaign that will not require resupply from home
  3. Provide private goods to soldiers to motivate them to fight.
  4. If the initial resources are not enough to win, give up the fight rather than drain the treasury
In contrast, BDM and Smith summarize Casper Weinberger's advice for Presidents contemplating war as follows:
  1. Commit forces to combat only if doing so is vital to the national interest
  2. If forces are committed, commit enough to win. If you aren't willing to commit the forces needed to win, than don't commit any at all.
  3. Have clearly defined political and military objectives, a clear cut plan for achieving them and the resources needed for doing so.
  4. Constantly reassess the relationship between objectives and forces committed and adjust them as needed.
  5. Before committing troops to combat, ensure that the action is supported by the people and Congress.
  6. Use force only as a last resort.
Though Sun and Weinberger offering completely different advice, BDM and Smith argue that each is offering very good advice to their intended recipient. Sun Tzu was giving advice to ancient kings who were leaders of small coalition regimes and Weinberger was giving advice to US Presidents who are leaders of large coalition regimes. Therefore, though the rules of warfare may be the same for both types of leaders, the rule of political survival are very different for leaders of small vs large coalition regimes.

In a small coalition regime, the leader (call him a dictator) survives in office with the support of a small coalition of supporters. Because they are small in number, the dictator can best ensure their loyalty by providing them with private benefits. As a result, the leader's survival depends not on his job performance as a national leader, but on his ability to keep the flow of private benefits to supporters going. As long as the private benefits flow to the leader's essential supporters, the leader is free to do whatever he wants with regard to policy, including the prosecution of a war. However, the leader will have only the resources he has left over after paying off his supporters to devote to the war effort. 

With this in mind, it should be clear that Sun Tzu's advice is tailor made for a dictator and we should expect dictators to behave in more of less this way. That is, we should expect them to act opportunistically and make bold, if economical, moves. While this may provide them with small scale successes, we should also expect them to fail with some frequency, either from miscalculation or lack of follow-on efforts.  In general, we should expect to see them fight wars on a shoe string budget and to avoid making large scale commitments of resources to the fight.

The leader of a large coalition regime (call her a democrat) is in an entirely different situation. She depends on the support of too many people (millions in the case of a democracy) to be able to pay them off with private benefits. Therefore, she stays in power by providing public benefits in the form of good (from the supporters point of view) public policy. As a result her political survival depends on her performance as a national leader in the eyes of these supporters. Where the dictator is largely free to do as he pleases with regard to prosecuting a war, the democrat has her head in a political noose as she will be called to account for all her decisions. She must make sure that the issue or cause at stake is one that her essential supporters care about and gauge how much these supporters will be willing to sacrifice to prevail. She must calculate whether the resources the supporters will deem appropriate to expend will in fact be enough to win the conflict. Then, if she engages in the war, she must not only win it, but do so in a seemingly competent manner. Anything less will open the door to a challenger for her job.

Indeed, Weinberger's  6 points pretty well cover the pre-war calculations a democrat must make if she wants to keep her job. Therefore, if we assume that democratic leaders are aware of the necessities of political survival, we should expect that they actually will  tend to act the way Weinberger argues they should. That is to say that they will tend to view war as a last resort, seek political consultations and support before engaging in action, and generally be more deliberate in initiating war. However, once they decide to fight, they are going to fight to win and devote significant resources to the process.

While the Ukraine crisis hasn't erupted into a full scale interstate war, Putin's actions and those of Western leaders seem too conform with the predictions of Selectorate Theory. Putin made a bold move to snatch Crimea at a very low cost but hasn't really followed up with much effort. He put large numbers of troops on the border but hasn't seen fit to use them in support of the separatists. Now, in the wake of the downing of Malaysian airliner, the Christian Science Monitor reports that he seems to have pulled a U-turn by telling his Security Council that there is no immediate threat from the west and suggesting that he might use his leverage to influence the separatists towards a peace process.

In contrast to Putin's staccato moves, leaders of more democratic nations may seem ponderous. But Selectorate Theory tells us that this is the nature of the beast. Democratic leaders must not get out ahead of their large coalition of supporters and pursue goals that the coalition does not deeply desire, and they must take care not to make mistakes (like giving high performance surface to air missiles to rebels) lest their supporters turn on them. However, if their supporting coalition demands action, then action they must have, though, again, that action must be successful (or at least perceived as being so). Western democracies may move plodding pace, but they find it hard to stop or change direction once committed to moving.

For this reason, Putin would be well advised to rein things in. The destruction of MH17 has struck a cord with the supporters of western democratic leaders and has probably increased domestic demands that those leaders do something. While it looks like we are a long way from European publics accepting the cost of boycotting Russian gas and oil (much less going to war),  the murder of close to 300 people is a step in that direction and will force western leaders to look harder for someway to demonstrate their competence to their supporters. Putin might do well to consider how he can allow them to do so at the least cost to himself and his coalition.

Monday, July 21, 2014

Factoid: US Auto Manufacturing

Mark Perry has a chart laden post about the US auto industry on his Carpe Diem blog that is worth checking out.

The chart I find most interesting is one that shows the Federal Reserves index of motor vehicles and parts productionin the US from 1972-2014 (below). Note that current production is about double what it was prior to 1993.


So what? Well, this just another factoid in my push-back against the notion that US manufacturing has vanished. That meme would have been true in the 1980s but hasn't been true since then. Note that, even at the height (or depth) of the Great Recession, the US produced about as many vehicle and parts as it did in the 1970s.

Of course, as is usually the case with manufacturing, higher output doe not mean higher employment. The chart below come from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and show employment in the US vehicles and parts industry.

 Employment in US Motor Vehicle and Parts Manufacturing Industry 1990-2014
Source: BLS
Sadly, BLS only has data from 1990 onward, but we can see enough in this chart, especially if we compare it to Perry's chart at top. Though production remained stable from 2000-2008 (top chart), the BLS graph shows that employment by roughly 300,000 in the same period. Of course, employment nose dived in the recession but has not comeback to pre-recession levels despite the fact that output is higher than it was before the recession.

From the society's point of view, this drop in employment is not a good thing (especially for Detroit). However, in terms of the auto industry, it is a sign of improved efficiency since manufacturers are making more vehicles and parts with about 500,000 less workers in 2014 compared to 2000. While hardly a rebirth, it is a significant improvement.

Of course, one needs to take care not to confuse the US auto industry with the Big Three (GM, Chrysler and Ford). As noted in Perry's post, 7 out of 10 of the best selling US auto mobiles are made by Toyota and Honda. Indeed, Cars.com, who published the 2014 American Made index  notes that there were only 13 cars that qualified as American made and 3 of them were being discontinued and so were not eligible for their top 10 list. That left every "American made" car on the top ten list (one wonders if there will be enough next year to have a top 10 list). As further evidence of the globalization of the US auto industry, Perry also notes that BMW is actually the largest exporter of vehicles from the US and that those exports have increased significantly since the end of the recession (see chart below).
From Mark Perry's Carpe Diem blog

Sunday, July 20, 2014

Matt Ridley on the Greening of the Planet


Matt Ridley (The Rational Optimist) points out that the planet is actually getting more green (in literal terms of vegetation coverage). It is important to point out that Ridley is not a climate change denier but takes an inquisitive empirical view of things. While he points out some inconvenient truths for the environmental movement, he argues that these are the result of the success of many environmental policies and should be a source of encouragement for environmentalists.

However, he questions many of the common wisdoms about the effect of economic growth on the environment and the benefit of renewable energy, especially bio-fuels.

Make sure you get to the part where he talks about Haiti and the Dominican Republic and his discussion of bio fuels at the end (it is only 18 minutes and goes by fairly quickly).



Saturday, July 19, 2014

Factoid: Russian Favorability Ratings Have Fallen in the Past Year



Pew Research's Global Attitudes Project released a report entitled Russia’s Global Image Negative amid Crisis in Ukraine. The general finding is that, in 20 of the 44 countries surveyed by Pew in this past April and May, people have a significantly more unfavorable view of Russia in 2014 than they did in 2013. The increase in unfavorable attitudes towards Russia is most profound in Europe and the US, as you can see in the graph below.



However, looking at regions obscures what is going on in individual countries. Therefore, it is important to look at country level data as shown in the next chart from Pew:
Note that the only countries in which a majority of respondents had a favorable view of Russia were China (66%, up 16 points from 2013), Bangladesh (60%), Greece (61%, down 2 points),  Vietnam (75%), and Russia itself (92%, up 8 points).

While these figures are undoubtedly affected by the Ukrainian crisis, we should remember that, among other things, Russia also hosted the winter Olympics in Socchi and has taken a pro-Assad stance in Syria in the 2013-2014 period. The latter may explain the improvement in Russia's favorability rating in Israel and the Palestinian territories.

If one looks closely at the nations in which a smaller percentage of respondents had an unfavorable view of Russia (i.e., those with negative numbers in the shaded column on the right), one can see that several of those countries have a smaller percentage of respondents choosing to take either a favorable or unfavorable view at all. For instance, 7% less respondents in India had an unfavorable view of Russia in 2014 than in 2013, but only 55% of respondents expressed a favorable or unfavorable view in 2014, as opposed to 68% in 2013 (a 13% drop). In Pakistan, 51% of respondents expressed a favorable or unfavorable view of Russia other in 2013, but only 40% did in 2014 (an 11% drop). This is also true, to a lesser extent, in South Africa. This suggests a growing uncertainty about Russia in these countries

Indeed, the only countries that had an unambiguous increase in favorability towards Russia (beside Israel and the Palestinian territories) were China, the Philippines, and Russia itself.

In contrast,  global attitudes towards the US remain very favorable. In 34 of the 44 countries surveyed, a majority of respondents had a favorable view of the US (with Germany and China coming in at the bottom of the favorable pack with a 51% and 50% favorability respectively). As has been the case for years, the countries with less than 50% of respondents having a favorable view were mainly from the Middle East (Egypt, Jordan, Lebanon, Pakistan, Palestinian Territory, Tunisia, Turkey) with Russia, Greece and Argentina in the mix (the latter two's population possibly driven by disdain for US dominated financial markets and IGO's).

If one looks at the nations with the most favorable views of the US (i.e., those with 75% or more of the respondents reporting a favorable view of the US), the list includes some interesting nations. The Philippines had the most respondents with a favorable view (92%, 10% more than the US itself), and Vietnam and Bangladesh came in at 76% (about the same percentage the view Russia favorably).  It is also interesting to note that France makes this list at 75% of respondents having a favorable view of the US (which has been about the case since 2009 but  is a big improvement over the 37-43% ratings in France from 2003-2008).

Tuesday, July 15, 2014

Categorizing the Islamic State

Stathis N. Kalyvas has a post on the Monkey Cage, The logic of violence in the Islamic State’s war, in which he exams how the Islamic State (formerly the Islamic State of Iraq and Syria, or ISIS) uses violence. The question he asks is whether we should view the Islamic State as a sectarian or revolutionary group.

Though he cautions that the data is incomplete and somewhat contradictory, he argues that the Islamic State appears to be more a revolutionary group that happens to be Islamic than a predominantly Islamist group, as follows:

First, violence is not a transparent process and we should be careful about drawing easy conclusions from what transpires from the fog of the civil war battlefield. Second, there is nothing particularly Islamic or jihadi about the organization’s violence. The practices described above have been used by a variety of insurgent (and also incumbent) actors in civil wars across time and space. Therefore, easy cultural interpretations should be challenged. Third, if the Islamic State ought to be characterized, it would be as a revolutionary (or radical) insurgent actor. These groups project a goal of radical political and social change; they are composed of a highly motivated core, recruit using ideological messages (although not all their recruits or collaborators are ideologically motivated – far from it) and tend to invest heavily in the indoctrination of their followers. They tend to prevail over their less effectively organized insurgent rivals (see the examples of the Eritrean People’s Liberation Front or the Tamil Tigers in Sri Lanka), but their Achilles heel lies in their radical proclivities which often turn local populations against them if the opportunity arises, as happened in Iraq with al-Qaeda in Iraq. Revolutionary groups can appropriate a variety of other causes (nationalism, ethnic or sectarian identities), but their revolutionary identity is central and helps make sense of much of their activity. In that respect, we have much to learn from revisiting the action and strategy of the last generation of insurgent revolutionary actors, those of the Cold War.
The big point I would like to make here is that, when interpreting ongoing events, one is forced to use theory by the lack of available data.  An essential part of using theory to analyze current events and make predictions about future events is deciding in what theoretical category the events belong. Are you looking at apples or oranges?

Elizabeth R. Nugent touches on the same subject in a MC post, What do we mean by ‘Islamist’?. She argues:
Islamism’s definition as an ideology that locates political legitimacy in the application of the sharia (often translated as Islamic law) and in Islamic tradition pegs it to complicated and unfixed concepts that are diversely interpreted in different manners by different practitioners. Various definitions of sharia draw from any combination of the prescriptions outlined in the Koran and the Sunnah related to larger societal issues of politics, economics, justice and social organization. The complexities arising from the translation of a multiplicity of practiced and interpreted Islams is manifested in the diverse range of actors that might fall under the rubric of an Islamist movement, party, or group. Islamists can range from those that advocate for quietism, effecting gradual political change through internal individual reform, to political parties advocating for societal reform through social welfare and electoral contestation, to revolutionary militants that seek to overthrow illegitimate states and implement revolutionary change. Islamists range from those who root justifications of their political behavior in personal and literalist interpretation of the textual tradition, to those who rely on interpretations derived from independent reasoning and decision-making with a firm basis in established schools of Islamic legal theory.
She concludes:

In many ways, this finding and the larger point are obvious and intuitive, but it’s something that continues to get lost in contemporary debates. It means both actors and critics who essentialize Islam, and fault or credit the entire faith tradition for one politicized version contained within its discursive tradition, are incorrect. It’s why militant actors as well as religious parties cannot claim that they speak for all of Islam or Muslims as a collective community, and it’s why outsiders cannot condemn Islam as a monolithic entity. These differences in interpretation and practice are the fascinating and frustrating challenges in understanding religion in politics, and understanding the inherent multiplicity and pluralism contained with religious faith traditions is important for consumers of news about Islamism and its current political actors.




Matt Ridley on the Future Economy and Environment

Matt Ridley on why the future isn't as bad as a lot of people think.



Contemporary Protectionism: South Korean Tubular Steel

This past Saturday, Mark Perry commented on US tariffs on South Korean tubular steel. As he often does, he argues (a la Frederic Bastiat) that concerns about cheap steel imports reflect the interests of US steel producers at the expense of US steel consumers, the latter of which are actually more important to the society.

As Perry puts it:
If the viewpoint of the consumer, i.e. mankind, were seriously considered in the case of imported steel from Korea, there would be no question about the outcome – no government protection for the U.S. steel industry. And to get the lowest possible steel price for American consumers, we should welcome the Koreans to engage in as much “dumping” as they are willing to…. the lower the price they offer us, the better…. even if it’s below their cost of production… And if that’s really the case and they’re selling steel and steel pipe at a loss, we should gladly accept their generous gift of foreign aid to America, and stop complaining….
Of course, there is more than just consumers versus producers at stake. There is also the overall efficiency of the economy, which Perry argues is negatively impacted:
Economic trade theory and mountains of empirical evidence on protectionist trade policy confirm conclusively that there is almost always a net loss of economic efficiency from protectionist trade policies. Reason? Protectionist trade policies generate costs to domestic consumers in the form of higher prices and reduced trading activity that outweigh the benefits to protected domestic industries, often by a factor of 2-to-1. In other words, protectionist trade policies always makes the country imposing them worse off on net, not better off, when considering all of the costs and benefits.

Media Bias?

Perry also notes  that the WSJ's coverage of the issue displays "... the usual media bias of presenting protectionist trade policy completely from the viewpoint of the protected domestic industry." He then edits the WSJ article to reflect an emphasis on consumers

Typical of such reporting is this LA Times article by Don Lee which does seem to emphasize the effect on producers over that on consumers (despite mentioning a surge in demand for tubular steel due to fracking) and accepts the charge of "unfair" prices at face value. However, if you get deeper into the article, Lee does point out that US prices are out of line with the global market:
What's more, a deeper look at the industry also tells the story of a U.S. steel market that is out of sync with the rest of the world, where steel prices have been declining as Chinese real estate construction has softened.
Despite an international oversupply, U.S. Steel and other domestic operators charge substantially more than global competitors for tubular goods. That's possible, analysts said, because the industry has gone through severe restructurings over the last few decades and is now more concentrated with greater ability to dictate prices.
The article also notes that US steel manufacturers have contributed to the oversupply by ramping up production of tubular steel in anticipation of increased demand from the drilling industry. It isn't until close to the end of the article that the effect on US consumers (i.e., the energy industry) is brought  up and the tariffs are described in a quote as a two-edged sword.

Now, is this bias? Afterall, the article does get around to the main counterpoints and placing the emphasis on consumers is simply replacing one bias for another. I'll just leave at noting that is you read the article backwards, you might have a very different impression of the situation than if you read it as written.

Boudreaux Weighs In

Don Boudreaux has some even more scathing comments on a letter to the WSJ in which he puts the principle behind US tariffs in terms of individuals in households:
The ostensible principle behind Uncle Sam’s action is that we Americans are made poorer when non-Americans act especially vigorously to increase our access to foreign-made products.  But this principle is economically insane.  People grow prosperous, not by rejecting, but by embracing enhanced access to goods and services, regardless of the sources of this enhanced access.
If the principle that motivates Uncle Sam to tax Americans who buy inexpensive imports were valid, then, for example, my household would be made poorer whenever I buy - rather than make myself - my own furniture and clothing.  After all, Ethan Allen and Nordstrom charge prices so low that they not only “hurt,” they destroy, my capacity to make for myself the goods that they offer for sale.  Should I perhaps, in my quest to grow more prosperous, hire my neighbor to threaten to shoot me whenever I seek out merchants willing to sell to me especially low-priced sofas and shirts?


Friday, May 16, 2014

BDM and Smith on Ukraine's Political Future

Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and Alastair Smith published a piece in Foreign Affairs, Ukraine's Last Best Hope: How Political Reform Can Defend Against Russian Intervention.

For my students that have had a belly-full of Selectorate Theory this past term, the argument will be a familiar one. In short, Ukraine's best hope is to reform its political system into one that requires a large coalition of essential supporters for leaders to stay in power. Such a system will provide leaders with the incentive to provide good public policy, as opposed to private benefits to essential supporters, and to try hard at it. Hard as in, as if their political survival depended on it because it would.

In Ukraine's case, establishing a government that requires a broad base of support will assure people in Eastern Ukraine that the government in Kiev will meet their needs. BDM and Smith argue that this is they way to deal with the demands of the Russian speaking population and to quell their desire for secession. As they put it:
Apart from all of these needed reforms, of course, there is the question of what to do about the Russian bear in the woods. Here, a few principles should govern the Ukrainian government’s response. Self-determination is a fundamental right advanced by coordination freedoms and competitive elections. The way to win the support of blocs of citizens is to provide them with effective public policies that advance their well-being. When governments fail to do that, then citizens naturally look for alternatives, either by selecting a new government or, in extremis, seeking to secede. Secession is the manifestation of failed government; precluding it by fiat is not the solution. Rather, providing incentives not to secede is the goal, attainable by structuring government so that leaders need the support of a broad base of society to stay in power and, consequently, must reward many people through effective policy.
 Democratic societies, in which leaders cater to as many people as possible, are virtually immune to coups, revolution, and civil war. The French political system withstood citizens taking to the barricades in the late 1960s, as did the U.S. political system during the Vietnam War. India, likewise, has withstood regular protests of government policies over the years because, in the end, most citizens recognize that they can redress grievances through normal political channels if enough of them express dissatisfaction with their government’s policies. To win over the hearts and minds of pro-Russian Ukrainians, the government in Kiev needs to make Ukrainian citizenship more valuable than defecting to Russia. But so far, the government’s responses to the unrest in eastern Ukraine have failed to do so. Kiev ought to balance resource allocations fairly, assure the freedoms and rule of law, and then gamble on a self-determination referendum later. Only then will the new government be able to convince many eastern Ukrainians that it is better to be Ukrainian than Russian.
During the Cold War, Western leaders seized any opportunity to score points against Russia. But today is not the Cold War, and a decade of U.S. involvement in Afghanistan and Iraq has tarnished the allure of military intervention. It is almost unthinkable today that the United States or NATO would intervene in Ukraine to thwart Russian ambitions. But given the ineffectiveness so far of sanctions, rather than confronting Russia, Western politicians today should focus on promoting a free and prosperous society in Ukraine. In the long run, such a transformation will prove to be a stalwart opponent to Russia’s expansion; democracies are hard to push around. The stars are aligned in Ukraine’s favor. Making real change toward democracy is the best weapon in the West’s arsenal.

Wednesday, May 14, 2014

The Green Nature of Markets or The Problem with Environmental Fads and Dogma

A couple of friends of mine were buying a futon when the saleswoman came up and said, "What you need to know about these is that they don't use any wood from the rain forest." One of my friends replied, "That doesn't matter. We're economists, all we care about is the price." My other friend said that the saleswoman just guppied for a minute before stammering, "Well...I guess that's a point of view."

Yes, it is a point of view and an extremely good one. This is because prices are the mechanism by which we get signals from the market about the relative costs and values of things. When one thing is cheaper than another, we know that either less resources were used to produce it or that it is less valued by other consumers. In the case of two identical products (say two futons), we can more or less ignore the second possibility and focus on the first. Therefore, when purchasing products, buying things that are lower priced will generally result in buying things that took less resources to produce.

In 2010, Stephen Budiansky offered what he called Math Lessons for Locavores.
But the local food movement now threatens to devolve into another one of those self-indulgent — and self-defeating — do-gooder dogmas. Arbitrary rules, without any real scientific basis, are repeated as gospel by “locavores,” celebrity chefs and mainstream environmental organizations. Words like “sustainability” and “food-miles” are thrown around without any clear understanding of the larger picture of energy and land use.
The result has been all kinds of absurdities. For instance, it is sinful in New York City to buy a tomato grown in a California field because of the energy spent to truck it across the country; it is virtuous to buy one grown in a lavishly heated greenhouse in, say, the Hudson Valley.

Budiansky goes on to look at the claims made by "locavores" about the energy that is wasted on shipping food over great distances and generally debunks them. Among other things he notes that it only takes one tablespoon of diesel fuel to move 1 pound of produce 3,000 miles by rail (which is totally credible since railroads get 476 ton/miles to the gallon). He also notes that transportation only accounts for 14% of the energy used in food production. In contrast, home preparation and storage account for 32%, so consumers are the real energy hogs.

As interesting as this all may be, focusing on energy alone ignores all the other resources that go into food production. As Budiansky puts it:

The best way to make the most of these truly precious resources of land, favorable climates and human labor is to grow lettuce, oranges, wheat, peppers, bananas, whatever, in the places where they grow best and with the most efficient technologies — and then pay the relatively tiny energy cost to get them to market, as we do with every other commodity in the economy. Sometimes that means growing vegetables in your backyard. Sometimes that means buying vegetables grown in California or Costa Rica.
Gee, wouldn't it be nice if we had some sort of system that made sure that things were produced in the most favorable locations, using the most efficient technologies and that took differing costs of transportation into account.

Excuse my sarcasm but this is exactly what markets do. If someone can find a way to make it cheaper enough somewhere else that it pays to ship the product of log distances, then they make a killing on it and consumers get lower priced produce.

In North Carolina, we have lots of hog and poultry farms be cause the climate here is very conducive to that type of operation (and not conducive to other things). These farms consume far more corn feed than North Carolina  produces. They only exist because the railroads found a way to inexpensively ship corn from the midwest. The key innovation there was the Big John covered hopper and the use of unit trains that carry only one commodity from point A to B. This allowed the growth of large meat packing firms like Smithfield which became the largest pork producer in the world. A lot of people in NC are totally ignorant of this railroad connection, even if they are aware if the size of the hog and poultry industry

But that's okay, we don't need to know all that because most of the relevant information is aggregated into the price. As Landsburg points out in reference to Budiansky's article: 
The key economic point is that in practice, there is one and only one way to account for all those costs (or at least most of them) and that is to look at the price of each tomato, which largely reflects the opportunity costs of the land, the workers, the farm equipment, the resources that produce that farm equipment, and much more that matters very much but that you and I probably won’t think of on our own. 
To be sure, markets aren't perfect, especially where externalities are concerned. But we need to realize that they are inherently "green" in the sense that they incentivize efficiency which is the essence of conservation. However, this efficiency only works when  people follow the incentives. Where consumers are concerned, this means buying things that are lower priced. If a locally grown tomato sell for less, by all means buy it. But if it costs more than one from California, it probably means that more resources were used to produce the local one, and you should buy the one from California if you care about conserving resources.

Of course, there is the possibility that the local farmer is just as efficient as the California one, but knows that a lot of people irrationally (as I have argued above) value local produce and will pay a higher price. Power to the farmer that can do this but his customers are playing the role of the Greater Fool in the farmer's plans.

On a personal note...

My wife and I have four chickens that I keep in my yard and this is supposedly sustainable agriculture. We get 3 eggs a day which are very tasty, so they are worth twice as much to me as the eggs I can buy in the supermarket. Therefore, I would put there value at $4/dozen which comes out to $30 of eggs per month.. Against that I have the cost of feed and other supplies which run about $20/month. This means I get $10 of value each month. However, I spent $1,500 building the coup and purchasing the chickens and other sundries. So I won't break even until 150 months or 12.5 years have passed. Of course, by then I will have needed to acquire several more generations of chickens and the coup will need maintenance, pushing the break even date farther into the future.

Of course, I haven't mentioned the labor involved in all this. My wife spends about 4 hours a month tending the chickens. Even at minimum wage (which dramatically undervalues her time), that's $29 of labor costs. So we are actually losing $19/month before I even begin to calculate my labor for building the coup (another $300 because that took me a while).

My point is that there is nothing sustainable about any of this. Our piddly little operation burns up far more resources than it produces. Sure the eggs taste better, but we end up giving half of them away because we just don't need 21 eggs a week.

In contrast, the professionals make a profit selling eggs for less than $2/dozen. They are the ones who are conserving resources and sustainably producing eggs and poultry, not us. We have some pet chickens we love and my wife especially enjoys tending them. Keeping chickens is entirely a leisure activity which puts it in the category of consumption not production. The eggs are simply a by product that lowers its overall cost (perhaps making it sustainable consumption). That's the only way our chicken endeavor makes any sense to me. (Actually, it is something my wife really likes and that's all I need to know.)

Tuesday, May 13, 2014

More on Externalities: Pigou and Coase

I found a very readable blog post by Stephen Landsburg on the contributions of Ronald Coase that also covers the basics of English economist Arthur Cecil Pigou's theory of externalities.

While I highly recommend reading Landsburg's post itself, the short versions is this. Pigou identified the problem of externalities (i.e., cost of transactions that were not born by the transacting parties) and proposed a straight-forward solution, internalize the cost by imposing a tax equal to the cost of the externality (what is known as a Pigovian tax). Pigou's primary argument wasn't that this was fair (though it certainly seems so) but that, by incorporating the costs into transactions,  the market would produce optimum levels of external costs. In terms of pollution, it would mean that we would get neither too little pollution (at the cost of more valuable economic activity) nor too much of it.

Coase proposes a wrinkle to this argument that made many people's head explode. He argued that it wasn't clear who was imposing costs on who. As Landburg sums it up:
If you breathe the pollution from my factory, I’m imposing a cost on you—but at the same time, you’re imposing a cost on me. After all, if you lived somewhere else, you wouldn’t be complaining about the smoke and I wouldn’t be getting punished for it.

While this example might seem a bit bizarre, consider the 19th century problem of railroads running through farms. If farmers plant their crops too close to the tracks, sparks from the old steam engines could (and did) set the fields on fire. Since the externality originates with the railroad, Pigou would argue that they should bear the costs of ant fire damage. But according to Coase, the farmer's choice of planting close to the tracks is as much of a factor as the railroad's choice to run trains down them. Furthermore, if the railroad is held accountable for the cost of fire, farmers have no incentive to avoid planting close to the tracks.

Here is where Coase's ideas become really interesting. Suppose that it would be cheaper for have farmers not plant within 50 feet of the tracks  than it would be to have the railroad compensate the farmers for fire losses. This might well be the case since fires destroy entire fields and not planting 50 feet of crops along the track would not reduce output by much. If this was the case, it would be more efficient to impose the cost of the externality on the farmer rather than on the railroad. Conversely, imposing the cost on the railroad would not be the optimum solution as farmers would have no incentive to keep their crops back and more fires would result.

Of course, in a perfect world where parties could costlessly negotiate with one another, it wouldn't matter what the rule was. If railroads were charged with paying damages for every crop fire and it was much cheaper to have farmers not plant near the tracks, the railroad could simply pay farmers to keep their crops back. The railroad would have to pay out less money and the farmers would be compensated for the loss in production. Such bargaining over externalities is known as Coasian Bargaining and the Coase Theorem argues that, if transaction costs for such bargaining are sufficiently low, then it will not matter what rules the government establishes. The parties involved will work out the most efficient solution among themselves.

Unfortunately, the real world is fraught with transaction costs that would make it hard for railroads to do this with large numbers of farmers. Therefore, the liability rules established by the government will matter and they can produce more or less efficient results depending on the specifics of the situation. Sometimes, indeed very often, a Pigovian tax or similar solution is the best way to go, other times not. In the example above, it would be more efficient to have the farmers not plant close to the tracks and the best rule may be that farmers are not allowed to plant with so many feet of the tracks.

As Landsburg points out, the real message Coase has for us is to move away from an obsession with identifying who is at fault and focus more on finding an efficient solution to the problem. Though the theory can not say what the best solution would be in any given situation, it does suggest that having the parties negotiate is a good approach in general. Landsburg notes that Coases's work led to the development of the field of law and economics.

On a tangential note, Abraham Lincoln gained prominence as a lawyer when he successfully argued a case for the Rock Island Railroad before the Supreme Court that dealt with externalities. The railroad had a bridge across the Mississippi that was struck by a riverboat. The boat owner sued for damages, claiming the bridge was a hazard to navigation. This was 1857, railroads were new and this bridge was the first one over the Mississippi. At stake was the right of railroads to build bridges over navigable rivers without being liable for every boat that bumped into them. Lincoln's victory established the liability rule (i..e, that the boat operator's are liable) that allowed railroads to span rivers (not a trivial matter for subsequent US economic development). [And, yes, Honest Abe was a corporate lawyer to the extent that he counted railroads like the Illinois Central among his biggest clients.]

Note: Lansburg also provides a link to Coases's 1960 paper "The Problem of Social Costs."

Monday, May 12, 2014

Matt Ridley on Differences between Economists and Ecologists

Matt Ridley, who bills himself as the Rational Optimist, has a post on his blog about "Why most resources don't run out" that looks at the different views that economists and ecologists have about natural resources.

He notes that ecologists frequently argue that natural resources are being exhausted at an unsustainable rate and are running out. Ridley 'had me at hello' here because I grew up during the first oil crunch in the 1970s and remember the dire warnings that we only had so many years (20 or 30) of oil left.Yet, here we are four decades later and we still have plenty of oil. Indeed according to BP's 2013 Statistical Review of World Energy, we had 52.9 years of oil at the end of 2012, up from 48.3 years a decade earlier.

Note that in the 10 years since 2002, when we supposedly had 48.3 years of oil left, we didn't go from 48.3 to 38.3 as you would expect, but we went from 48.3 to 52.9. This sort of reminds me of the line from "The Polar Express" in which the annoying kid says, "Come on, it's been 5 minutes to midnight for the last half hour."

Ridley comments on this foible among projected limits of resources:
But here's a peculiar feature of human history: We burst through such limits again and again. After all, as a Saudi oil minister once said, the Stone Age didn't end for lack of stone. Ecologists call this "niche construction"—that people (and indeed some other animals) can create new opportunities for themselves by making their habitats more productive in some way. Agriculture is the classic example of niche construction: We stopped relying on nature's bounty and substituted an artificial and much larger bounty.
Economists call the same phenomenon innovation. What frustrates them about ecologists is the latter's tendency to think in terms of static limits. Ecologists can't seem to see that when whale oil starts to run out, petroleum is discovered, or that when farm yields flatten, fertilizer comes along, or that when glass fiber is invented, demand for copper falls.
That frustration is heartily reciprocated. Ecologists think that economists espouse a sort of superstitious magic called "markets" or "prices" to avoid confronting the reality of limits to growth. The easiest way to raise a cheer in a conference of ecologists is to make a rude joke about economists.

The big point here is that ecologists often take static views of resource stocks and consumption rates when projecting trends forward. In contrast, economists see supplies and consumption rates as dynamic and changing in response to relative scarcities.

Take oil. When the supply of oil decreases, the price goes up. People respond by using less oil and trying harder to find more. If the price goes up enough supplies of oil that were previously economically nonviable will become viable. Also, higher prices give people an incentive to develop new technologies to extract oil, such as hydraulic fracking.

Mark Perry provided this graph showing the amount of energy the US uses per $1 of  Real GDP (i.e., adjusted for inflation). Note that from 1970 (when energy prices started rising significantly) to 2013, the amount of energy of all types used to produce $1 of GDP shrunk from 14.4 thousand BTUs to 6.2 thousands BTUs. This is a 57% reduction in 43 years.


Of course, the US is using more energy because our Real GDP grew 238% in the same period. But the point is that if, back in 1970, you had projected that the US economy would grow 238% and used 1970 energy intensities to calculate the amount of energy the US would be using, you would over estimate today's energy consumption by 142%. Put another way, we are only using 41% of the energy to produce our current level of GDP as we would have had to use to produce the same amount with 1970 technologies and usage rates.

This is not the result of "superstitious magic" but the working of the market and, to a debatable extent, the effects of government policies. There should not be anything mysterious about the fact that, when a resource becomes more scarce, its price rises. Nor should there be anything unfathomable about consumers responding to a rise in price by using less or producers responding by producing more. Indeed, it is more unfathomable to assume that consumers and producers will not change their behavior in the face of changing prices as ecologists do when they project current patterns of behavior forward.

Ridley gives an example of the difference between the way ecologists and economists look to the future with regard to food production:
In his recent book "The View from Lazy Point," the ecologist Carl Safina estimates that if everybody had the living standards of Americans, we would need 2.5 Earths because the world's agricultural land just couldn't grow enough food for more than 2.5 billion people at that level of consumption. Harvard emeritus professor E.O. Wilson, one of ecology's patriarchs, reckoned that only if we all turned vegetarian could the world's farms grow enough food to support 10 billion people.
Economists respond by saying that since large parts of the world, especially in Africa, have yet to gain access to fertilizer and modern farming techniques, there is no reason to think that the global land requirements for a given amount of food will cease shrinking any time soon. Indeed, Mr. Ausubel, together with his colleagues Iddo Wernick and Paul Waggoner, came to the startling conclusion that, even with generous assumptions about population growth and growing affluence leading to greater demand for meat and other luxuries, and with ungenerous assumptions about future global yield improvements, we will need less farmland in 2050 than we needed in 2000. (So long, that is, as we don't grow more biofuels on land that could be growing food.)

If the economists seem to be overoptimistic, consider this chart from the USDA showing the corn yield per acre in the US from 1983 to 2013. While there have been yearly fluctuations due to weather, the trend line shows that there has been over a 50% increase in the amount of corn produced on one acre of land in 30 years.
Keep in mind that the US agricultural industry was already one of the most technologically advanced in the world in 1983. Brad Plumer at WaPo's Wonkblog notes that US corn yields have increased dramatically since the 1940's. Prior to then, the average yield was between 20-30 bushels per acre. The recent yield of 158.8 bushels per acres is about a 600% increase over that level.  In the same period, the US population has only somewhat more than doubled.

If you look at the chart of US corn production per acre that Plumer provides (shown below) you get a sense of the expansion of production that is possible once an nation industrializes its agricultural sector. You also start to understand why Ridley has adopted the moniker of rational optimist.


Wednesday, May 07, 2014

The Three Faces of the Resource Curse

The Resource Curse hinges on the argument that a nation with large natural resources, such as oil, will perform more poorly than nations that do not possess such resources. This was originally an economic concept and the performance in question was the economic growth of the economy. As Jeffrey Frankel described it in a 2010 NBER working paper:
It has been observed for some decades that the possession of oil, natural gas, or other valuable mineral deposits or natural resources does not necessarily confer economic success. Many African countries such as Angola, Nigeria, Sudan, and the Congo are rich in oil, diamonds, or other minerals, and yet their peoples continue to experience low per capita income and low quality of life. Meanwhile, the East Asian economies Japan, Korea, Taiwan, Singapore and Hong Kong have achieved western-level standards of living despite being rocky islands (or peninsulas) with virtually no exportable natural resources. Auty (1993, 2001) is apparently the one who coined the phrase “natural resource curse” to describe this puzzling phenomenon. Its use spread rapidly.

Therefore, we can look at slower economic growth and development as the first face of the Resource Curse.

In The Dictators Handbook, Bueno de Mesquita and Smith argue that having valuable natural resources can promote the development and survival of autocratic governments, thus putting a second or political face on the Resource Curse.  The argument here is that natural resources provide an income stream for political leaders that is largely independent of the government's economic policies. Resources such as oil, lumber, and minerals can be extracted without having a well functioning economy and a productive workforce (beyond those involved in the resource industries). Income from the resources provides a steady and easily controlled stream of income from which autocratic leaders can pay off their essential supporters and, thus, remain in power.

Because, such leaders are not primarily dependent on tax revenue from the domestic economy, they have little incentive to invest in public goods such as infrastructure and education that would promote economic growth (and greater tax revenue). Indeed, they face incentives to do the opposite in order to prevent the larger population from organizing a revolution to change the system. After all, the freedoms and resources that people need to conduct economic activities can also be used to carry out political activities that might threaten the regime. Being independent of tax revenue allows autocrats resource rich to deny these public goods to the population, and thus stay in power in addition to keeping the bulk of the nation poor.

In a recent post on the Monkey Cage, Ross and Voeten argue that resource wealth, specifically oil wealth has a third, global face to it. As they put it:
If a government anticipates that it can sell its main export irrespective of its foreign policy behavior, then abiding by bothersome international norms and institutions becomes less of a priority. A large fraction of the world’s rogue regimes – Iran, Venezuela, Sudan, Libya (under Qaddafi) and Iraq (under Saddam) – are financed by oil wealth.
They note that as most nations become economically and socially globalized,  they face incentives to become politically globalized by joining intergovernmental organizations and agreements. They also have incentives to international political norms to assure economic partners that they will also adhere to economic institutional norms. However, Ross and Voeten find that this is not the case for oil-rich nations. In their words:
We find that beyond a certain level of oil income (around $100 per capita) more oil wealth is correlated with sharply lower levels of political globalization.  Strikingly, this pattern shows up when we compare oil-rich states to oil-poor states, and when we look at individual states over time, as their oil production rises and falls. The findings also hold when we control for possibly confounding factors, such as democracy, economic development, and regional effects. We find very similar effects when we use other indicators to measure the degree to which states are integrated into and cooperate with international institutions.
This leads to what Ross and Voeten call "unbalanced globalization" and they argue it produces a set of nations upon which we are economically dependent but which are not "well integrated into the world’s political and legal institutional infrastructure".

Friday, May 02, 2014

What To Do About Development In Poor Nations

Dani Rodrik writes that he like to ask his economic development students whether they would rather be rich in a poor country or poor and rich country? He clarifies the question by defining a rich nation as being in the top 10% of all nations ranked by average per capita income and a poor nation as being in the bottom 10%. He defines being rich as being someone in the top 10% of the country’s income distribution, while being poor means being in the bottom 10%. He notes that most of his students respond by saying they would rather be rich in a poor country, but argues that the data shows that his students are way off.
According to Rodrick’s calculations, the average poor person in a rich country earns three times more than the average rich person in a poor country. Adjusted for differences in purchasing power parity, the median income of the bottom 10% in rich nations is $9,400, while the median income of the richest 10% in poor nations is only $3,000. He goes on to note that other indicators of well-being, such as infant mortality, also support the argument that it is better to be poor in a rich nation, then rich and poor nation (Rodrik, 2011, p 135-136) [All references listed here]

What this strongly suggests is that, somehow or other, the richer nations in the world have developed a political economic system that is unarguably superior to those of poor nations. Underlying this conclusion is, of course, the view that wealth is created, not expropriated and, therefore, the rich nations have not got rich by exploiting the poor nations. However, even if we make this intellectual leap over the theories of Marx, Lenin, and Wallersteen, we are left with the question of what it is about the political economies of rich nations that make them rich, and how can poor nations can improve their own systems?

In answering these questions, it may be helpful to categorize the obstacles to development as being in political, economic, or social realms. In the political realm, the more prosperous nations have created a powerful central government that has, in Bates’s (2001) terms, domesticated violence in the society and have resolved what Weingast (1995) calls the fundamental political dilemma of the state by restraining state power so that its policies are not predatory. According to Selectorate Theory (Bueno de Mesquita et. al. 2003), this latter condition will only be met if the nation’s political leader depends on a large coalition of supporters so that the leader must provide public rather than private goods to supporters. In the economic realm, rich nations have established what Acemoglu and Robinson (2012) describe as inclusive economic institutions that provide the freedom and incentives necessary for the larger part of the population to actively participate in economic production and wealth generation. In the social realm, the rich nations have both provided their citizens with adequate education and information to exploit the economic opportunities available to them as well as providing the mental space needed to do so as described by Banerjee and Duflo.

These categories or realms are far from distinct.  They overlap in many places as well as have causal effects on one another. For instance, a small coalition political regime will not only be predatory but will tend to set up extractive economic institutions (Acemoglu and Robinsons, 2012) and provide limited education to the population (Bueno de Mesquita and Smith, 2011). At the same time, as poor and uneducated population will lack the information and mental space either to fully exploit the economic opportunities available to them (Banerjee and Duflo, 2011) or challenge the political system (Bueno de Mesquita and Smith, 2011).

Therefore, the question of how to spur the development of poorer nations does not admit to simple answers. Focusing on changes in one category runs the risk of overlooking needed changes in the others or, worse, failing to foresee how aspects of the other categories might confound the desired effects of changes in the first.

Economic theories of development are arguably prone to making this mistake to a greater or lesser extent. Neoclassical growth theory is perhaps most open to this criticism as it assumes that property rights are established and enforced in the political realm and that individuals are fully informed and rational in the social realm. Even when economic theories of development, such as North’s theory of institutions, recognize the inadequacy of institutions and the limits of the assumption of economic rationality, they still tend to assume that the government has an interest in improving the economic performance of the economy at large.  This assumes away the political problems that must be solved in order for their policy prescriptions to be effective.

This is not to say that economists are unaware or willfully ignorant of these political problems.  They are very aware of them and some, like Acemoglu and Robinson (2012), try to incorporate political factors into their theories and analysis. However, everybody has an area of expertise within which they focus and a set of analytic tools which give them more leverage on one set of issues than on another.  Therefore, each researcher gives answers to a subset of the questions involved in economic development.
It is all too natural to suggest that researchers should expand their scope and bridge gaps between different approaches. Better yet, one might seek a unifying theory to simultaneously consider political, economic and social issues at the same time.  However, bridges take a long time to build, unifying theories tend to be elusive, and, in the meantime, policy makers must act. (Not to mention that students must answer essay questions about what advice to give them.).

So what can we glean from the partial answers of extant research with regard to the political, economic and social realms?

Political: It is tempting to give the political realm pride of place in fostering development over the economic and social realms for two reasons.  First, establishing a central political power that can domesticate violence seems to be prerequisite for any meaningful economic growth. Second, once a hegemonic state is established, reining it in becomes the primary concern, which is itself a political problem.  This suggests that Bate’s (2001) domestication of violence and resolution of Weingast’s (1995) fundamental political dilemma must historically precede other changes needed to spur long term economic growth.  Selectorate Theory and Acemoglu & Robinson (2012) would both argue that the fundamental political dilemma would only be solved by having a political system that required leaders to have large coalition of support. In theoretical terms, these political developments are necessary conditions for growth and prosperity.

It is important to note that a necessary condition is, by definition, one that must be met for something to occur, but is not sufficient to produce the occurrence of that thing.  Therefore, the argument is not that the establishment of a strong central government that requires a broad coalition of support will produce long term economic growth but that a lack of such a government will prevent it.

Acemoglu and Robinson (2012) would also provide an important caveat that short to medium term growth, perhaps lasting as long as several decades, is possible under extractive political institutions (what Selectorate Theory would call a small coalition regime)  if the ruling elites are confident in their power and can control the flow of resources.  However, this growth will fizzle out once all the opportunities for growth through investing and adopting existing technologies are exploited. At that point, further growth would require domestic innovation and significant creative destruction which the elites will not allow to occur.

Economic: In this realm in particular, Acemoglu and Robinson argue that prosperity depends on having inclusive economic institutions, which they define as follows:
those that allow and encourage participation by the great mass of people in economic activities that make best use of their talents and skills that enable individuals to make the choices they wish. To be inclusive economic institutions must feature secure property rights, an unbiased system of law, and provision of public services that provides a level playing field in which people can exchange and contract; it must also permit the entry of new businesses and allow people to choose their careers. (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2012, p 74-75)
Of course, this definition is very broad and focuses on what the institutions do more than on the particular form they take. This means that the problem of designing the right institutions to “encourage participation by the great mass of people in economic activities” is far from trivial.  Once fairly inclusive institutions are established (though their development and refinement will be ongoing), the majority of the economic theories of development also come into play.

Social: This is the realm in which people actually live and make the choices that the incentive structures of the economy and polity are intended to influence. As Banerjee and Duflo point out repeatedly, efforts to help the poor often fail for five reasons

  1. The poor often lack critical pieces of information or believe things that are not true.
  2. The poor bear too much responsibility for making decisions about too many aspects of their life.
  3. Markets may not be viable for things the poor need or they may face unreasonable prices for goods and services where markets are viable.
  4. Program failures in poor countries often have more to do with ignorance, ideology and inertia (the three I’s) than with poor governance and institutions.
  5. Expectations about what poor people are able and unable to do often turn into self-fulfilling prophesies. (Banerjee and Duflo, 2011, p 268-272)

It should be pointed out that Banerjee and Duflo (2011) argue against the notion that efforts to help the poor are doomed if the political and economic institutions are inadequate. They point to research that shows that much can be done within bad institutions and that these efforts may produce incremental changes in the institutions themselves.  For their part, Acemoglu and Robinson (2012), though arguing that such humanitarian efforts will not bring about prosperity, argue that, even if 90% of aid is siphoned off by elites, the 10% that gets to the poor may be very important for relieving their suffering. Indeed, Acemoglu and Robinson suggest that if aid is structured in a way that empowers people who are excluded by the political institutions, it may lead to future changes in the institutions.

So what do we do to promote development?

One approach, suggested primarily by Selectorate Theory, would be to distinguish between countries with small and large coalition regimes. Large coalition regimes would be expected to be motivated to improve the well-being of the larger society as the cheapest way to provide benefits to their supporting coalition. While they will still be biased towards policies that favor the segments of society that are in the supporting coalition and will be far from corruption free, the leaders of these governments will be held accountable for their nation’s economic performance. Therefore, they will be somewhat reliable partners in international efforts to promote development.

In contrast, leaders of small coalition regimes face incentives that require them to provide private benefits to a small group of supporters. Therefore, they can be expected to make every attempt to twist aid to that purpose.  Foreign aid is, therefore, likely to fail in its intended purpose and have the unintended consequence of bolstering the leader’s hold on power. This is particularly true of aid during an economic crisis when the leader is in danger of not being able to pay off his/her essential supporters and, thus, losing power.
Selectorate Theory suggests that the best approach is one of tough love and suspicious vigilance towards small coalition regimes. Aid should either be withheld to hasten the regime’s demise or tied to political reforms that will have the same effect. Humanitarian aid must be closely monitored and, if possible, given directly to its recipients.

Another, more incremental approach to political change is suggested by Acemoglu and Robinson (2012). As noted above, they argue that aid which empowers people excluded from political decision making may contribute to institutional drift towards more inclusiveness.

Of course, it could be argued that any international efforts at fostering political change in small coalition regimes will be resisted by the government if those efforts actually threaten (or appear to threaten) its hold on power.  Russia’s current crack down on NGOs seems to be a case of this.

Banerjee and Duflo (2011) seem to favor dealing directly with the dire needs of the impoverished and focusing on testing the effectiveness of programs to determine what works and what does not. Though their approach does not directly address the broader political questions, their focus on measuring effectiveness and only doing what is demonstrated to work implicitly takes government interference into account. That is to say if the government thwarts the program’s intended purpose, the data will show it. Thus, their emphasis on accountability based on scientific research methods provides an inherent and political neutral check on government interference.